Download file in PDF format: TRAC 1994: Romano-British Precious Metal Hoards: Some Comments on Martin Millett’s Paper (pp. 107–117)
Romano-British Precious-Metal Hoards: some comments on Martin Millett’s paper
by Catherine Johns
Lay not up for yourselves treasures on earth, where moth and rust doth
corrupt, and where thieves break through and steal:
But lay up for yourselves treasure in heaven, where neither moth nor rust
doth corrupt, and where thieves do not break through nor steal:
For where your treasure is, there will your heart be also.
(Matthew 6 19-21)
Investigation of the possible reasons behind the deposition and non-recovery of hoards in
antiquity is currently a fashionable area of research, and so it is not entirely unexpected to find
that scholars who have hitherto shown scant interest in Romano-British treasure (i.e. preciousmetal hoards) are now turning their attention to this class of evidence. For many years, the
focus of attention in Romano-British archaeology has been on economic theory, subconsciously
triggered by the importance of economic questions in modern society, on the development and
application of scientific and mathematical methods of analysis, and on fieldwork As Martin
Millett himself admits, artefact studies (other than pottery) have been neglected, except by a
few determinedly unfashionable scholars. The tendency to interpret a wide variety of
archaeological evidence in terms of religion and ritual, so typical of earlier generations, has
been somewhat out of favour, while art-historical methods have been anathema.
The pattern of academic research resembles the familiar fluctuations of fashion which are
found in so many aspects of life; study advances for a while on one front and then falls back to
allow another to become popular. fashions regularly recur after some time has elapsed, though
generally in a subtly altered form. There have been signs for some years that artefacts are
beginning to be noticed again, and the same would seem to be true of the role of ritual in past
societies. Those of us who have worked consistently for many years on subjects which were
outside the mainstream can only welcome the renewed interest of our colleagues, provided they
acknowledge the research that has been going on in what might be described as their
intellectual absence on other business.
Notwithstanding these incipient changes of research emphasis, many of the theoretical
issues raised by M. are not, in fact, new to those concerned with the Roman period, but have
been actively debated for many years. In particular, study of the dynamics of coin-hoarding has
given rise to an extensive literature. For a statement of what might be termed the pro-votive
view, together with references to other approaches and classifications, see Aitchison (1988).
Many of the points brought out by M. were discussed in characteristically lively fashion by 108 Catherine Johns
Richard Reece over eight years ago, in a paper which is surprisingly not cited in M . ‘s
references (Reece 1988).
The comments which follow were written in response to a draft of Martin Millett’s paper
which he circulated to a number of I have not seen his final text. From the complex
subject of treasure hoards, their contents and interpretation, he has selected certain specific
themes and ideas for discussion. I have done likewise, taking up points which seem to me to
invite challenge or further investigation, and dealing at some length with the definition of
votive hoards and objects, a subject which has become increasingly confused of late. I hope that
this section in particular will be seen as a useful contribution to the general debate on hoarding
in antiquity. Like M., I have not attempted to address all of the many issues involved since this
would be impossible in a short paper.
Research on Roman Precious-metal Objects
It is important to emphasise that over the last twenty-five years or so, considerable progress has
been made in this country and abroad on the study of the coins, silver plate and jewellery of the
Roman period which are found in precious-metal hoards. Many new discoveries have
augmented the body of evidence, and there is now enough published work for any interested
scholar to inform him- or herself and become qualified to join in the debate. It should hardly be
necessary to stress that familiarity with the state of knowledge on the artefacts is a prerequisite
for theorising about the assemblages. (For a summary of research on Roman silver plate since
Strong 1966 – still an invaluable source – see Johns 1990.)
The study of Roman precious-metal hoards is not, and never has been, a ‘British Museum
monopoly’. If this theme has been neglected in Britain outside the British Museum, the fault
lies not with curators but with outside scholars, who as free agents have opted to pursue other
lines of enquiry. It is wholly perverse to blame British Museum curators for the research
decisions of others: the study of Roman treasures, and access to the objects themselves, has
always been open and available to people working on Roman Britain and the Empire.
Continental and transatlantic scholars have been very active in these fields, and many have
studied material in the British Museum’s collections. Names such as Franc;:ois Baratte, Herbert
Cahn, Barbara Deppert-Lippitz, Michel Feugere, Annemarie Kaufmann-Heinimann, Ernst
Kiinzl, Marlia Mango, Max Martin, Stefanie Martin-Kilcher, Catherine Metzger, Andrew
Oliver and Kathleen Shelton spring to mind, but apart from Ernst Kiinzl’s magisterial
catalogue of the Neupotz find, reviewed in detail in an English magazine, M. does not cite any
of their work in his bibliography. (Kiinzl 1993: Painter 1994).
For very good reasons, in Britain scientific work on Roman precious-metal objects has been
centred in the British Museum Research Laboratory, but valuable research has been done in
Oxford, and Continental scientists have also made a major contribution The great importance
of scientific advances in the study of the material is ignored by M. Coin specialists, whose
crucial role in this whole debate is similarly given little weight by M., are based both within
and outside the British Museum. There is currently only one British Museum curator, the
present writer, with a special interest in the study of Roman silver plate and jewellery. Overall,
it is difficult to see how this picture can be described even by the most prejudiced observer as a
British Museum monopoly.
The accusation that scholarly interpretation has been influenced by the provisions of the
ancient English Treasure Trove law is unfounded, and worse, impugns the academic integrity
of those who work on the material It may not be widely understood that the British Museum Romano-British Precious-metal comments on Martin paper 109
has no financial vested interest in the legal status of a any museum which wishes to
acquire a treasure hoard has to pay the full market value for it whether it has been declared
Treasure Trove or not. The mechanisms for payment and the identity of the payee are different,
but the cost is always the market value of the material. Undoubtedly we should all prefer the
concept of the animus revertendi (the intention to retrieve) to be irrelevant in legal terms, and
perhaps eventually it will be, but consideration of whether or not it existed is important in
academic terms because it is germane to the interpretation of the dynamics of hoarding which
M is advocating
Alleged ‘Modern Values’
M. implies that those who work on Roman treasures have given little thought to the reasons for
their deposition, and that any attempts which have been made at interpretation have been based
on an unthinking assumption that modern value-systems were shared by people of the Roman
period. No reasonable person can be unaware of the fact that many beliefs and attitudes have
changed radically within the last century, let alone the last two millennia, and all serious
students of the past are acutely conscious of the need to free themselves from their own
culturally-conditioned preconceptions, difficult though that can be. [ made this point at some
length in my book Sex or Symbol (Johns 1982 144-148), but only because I was writing for the
general reader. J assumed all professionals were familiar with the problem.
[t is totally false to state, as M . does, that other researchers have been ‘assuming that
ancient values were similar or identical to those of the modern world’. Where some apparently
‘modern’ values are attributed to our forebears in Classical antiquity, it is not through
ignorance or default, but because, after due consideration, we believe that in those particular
instances. ancient and modern thinking broadly coincides. Far from imposing modern concepts
on our forebears, we have in some cases inherited theirs.
The truth is that in the past some cultural values were profoundly different from our own.
some were slightly different, while others were similar or virtually the same: we are studying
human beings in a different time and environment, not an alien species. L.P.Hartley’s dictum
‘the past is a foreign country; tlley do things differently there’ can be taken further; foreign
cultures. like the past. are not different from our own in eve,y single respect, they display many
similarities as well. The challenge is to identify the differences and similarities accurately. This
is a particularly daunting task when dealing with prehistory. The Roman world at least
provides a few pointers in the ancient literature.
The concealment of valuables for safekeeping, whether to be secured against potential theft
or to be drawn upon as a resource over a long period, is not a medieval or modern concept
imposed upon antiquity by unthinking twentieth-century museum curators; it is a known and
documented phenomenon of the Classical period. Consider, for example, the familiar New
Testament quotation at the head of this paper, or the Parable of the Talents (Matthew 25:
14-30), or the collection of references to the hoarding of Greek coinage brought together in
Melville Jones (1993 nos. 544-552)
Whatever may have been the case in prehistory, in the Roman period, coinage was the
medium of exchange, and gold, silver and bronze had a relationship which corresponds with
both medieval and modern perceptions of the relative values of different metals. It is therefore
hardly unreasonable to infer that bullion hoards had a special status in antiquity because of
their purchasing power, in addition to any other values they might have possessed, aesthetic,
magical, religious or sentimental. The latter are likewise perfectly familiar to post-Roman 110 Catherine Johns
perceptions. That objects could carry more than one level of significance or value is surely selfevident, and is indeed another example of similarity between the past and the present. The
Mildenhal\ Great Dish (Painter 1977b: no. 1) contains 8256 grammes of it is also an
example of artistic and technical excellence in silversmithing, and its iconography is full of
complex religious symbolism which would have carried a range of meanings: all of these
qualities were clearly important in antiquity and remain so today. It is when we see one quaJity
valued at the expense of others, as in the case of silver tableware treated solely as bullion
(Hacksilber), that we are alerted to an unusual situation. The classic case in Britain is that of
the treasure of Traprain Law (Curle 1923), which contains the broken remains of silver vessels
even more magnificent than those from Mildenhall. The excellent discussion of Hacksilber in
the account of the treasure from Gross Bodungen remains indispensable (Griinhagen 1954:
58- 70).
Like silver plate, gold jewellery had a negotiable value as bullion, but it was worn for
adornment and display and was therefore carefully selected for its appearance. The combination
of intrinsic and symbolic value has been characteristic of precious-metal and gem-set jewellery
in most societies, including our own (Johns 1995, forthcoming).
Incidentally, while M. is criticising us for supposedly applying to antiquity the ‘modern’
perception that gold and silver are of high value, another scholar, Michael Vickers, has for
many years been denouncing the notion that pottery, such as Greek painted vases or terra
sigillata, could ever have been regarded as a luxury material in the Classical he
attributes this view to 19th/20th century ideas about aesthetic value, that is, to modern
perceptions imposed upon the past! (See, most recently, Vickers 1994).
Distribution of Romano-British Precious-metal Hoards
Two subjects which are important to the understanding of hoard deposition require closer
scrutiny than they have received from M., (I) the perceived distribution of known gold and
silver hoards from Roman Britain and (2) the meaning of ‘votive’, especially as it may affect
the animus revertendi required by the traditional Treasure Trove law, and hence the imagined
influence upon scholars who are thought to prefer Treasure Trove verdicts.
Hoards which are known to archaeology are those which were not recovered by their
owners or depositors in antiquity, which were not found and used in medieval or modern times,
and which are not still lying undiscovered in the ground. Hoards which were legitimately
retneved by their owners or appropriated by others in antiquity, those found in the intervening
centuries and melted down for re-use, and those which are still buried are not present in the
record. A statement of the obvious, perhaps, but what proportion do these known and reported
hoards represent of the treasures originally buried for safekeeping or any other reason? Though
we cannot know, it is likely to be a very small percentage.
Legislation and practice to deal with buried treasure evolved in Britain and other countries
in the Middle Ages. As M. points out, this circumstance reflects the value to the Crown and
Treasury of gold and silver at that period. It also reflects the fact that treasure was unearthed
often enough to attract some kind of standard procedure rather than an ad hoc response. We
can only speculate about the quantity of prehistoric, Roman and early Medieval bullion which
must have been found and absorbed by the Exchequer even by the 12th century, when the law
reached a semblance of its present form.
In Britain, the earliest discovery of Roman silver plate of which we have a record is the
Risley Park Lanx, found in June 1729 (Stukeley 1736: Johns Johns & Painter 1991): Romano-British PrecIOus-metal Hoards: comments on lv/arlin Millett’s paper 111
records of the discovery of Roman coin hoards go back further. but only to the 16th century.
Elsewhere in Europe, it was also in the eighteenth century that scholars began to record such
finds on a fairly regular basis. The number of recorded or surviving seventeenth-century finds
of Roman plate is very small, and earlier ones are extremely rare (e.g. the cup from Arras now
in Vienna, found in 1568: Baratte & Painter 1989: no. 1 see also the Empire-wide summary
in Oliver 1977 16-18) Several 18th and 19th century finds from Britain are still extant,
though few contextual details have been preserved. The Backworth treasure, for example, found
about 1811, is probably not from Backworth itself. but from elsewhere in Northumberland
(Hawkins 1850)
The apparent pre-eminence of East Anglia observed by M. on today’s distribution map is
based on the discovery and reporting of several large and spectacular plate and jewellery hoards
in the twentieth century, specifically within the last 50 years, amounting to a little over 3% of
the time which has elapsed since the Roman period. The only important item of Roman silver
plate from East Anglia known to have been found in earlier generations is the Mileham dish,
which came to Iigllt in 1839 (Walters 1921: no. 87: Kent & Painter 1977: no. 103) Land use,
agricultural methods, metal-detecting and media hype a\1 affect the rate of discovery and
reporting. Noteworthy finds stimulate increased searching activity in the areas where they were
located. The fact that in recent decades East Anglia has also produced important prehistoric
and early medieval finds of gold and silver may, as M. suggests, indicate a long tradition of
such burials in that area in antiquity, and if so, this is clearly a matter of great interest.
However, a concentration of11Oards of widely separated date is perhaps more likely to constitute
evidence of a 20th century phenomenon concerned with their recovery and reporting, and/or a
history of discovery and destmction of such finds in other areas in the medieval and early
modern periods. This is a subject which certainly requires more searching analysis.
I would therefore counsel the greatest caution in drawing any conclusions based on the
currently-known geographical or chronological span of precious-metal hoards from Roman
Britain, as the evidence, although more extensive than that from most European countries, is
still extremely limited. It may be significant that late-Roman gold and silver coin-hoards,
which are far more numerous than treasures containing plate and jewellery, do not reveal a
concentration in East Anglia: if anything, there is a slight emphasis on the West Country
(Archer 1979: King Robertsonforlhcoming).
Votive Hoards
It may be as a result of recent work by prehistorians (notably Bradley 1990) that the definition
of votive or ritual deposits has become so contentious and so fashionable. M. believes that some
scholars working on treasures have been unwilling to admit the possibility of religious or votive
deposition as opposed to the practical purpose of the safekeeping of valuables because votive
status would imply the absence of the animus revertendi on the part of the original owner. and
would therefore preclude a Treasure Trove verdict under the traditional mles.
This idea is based on confusion about the meaning of votive. An overtly religious or votive
hoard could perfectly well have been buried with the intention of recovering it later. Vofum is a
vow, a promise made to a deity in return for or in the hope of the granting of a favour.
Figuratively it could denote a wish, desire or prayer: a vow to a god could be in the form of an
action rather than the gift of an object. (For a good general discussion, see Henig 1984).
Items dedicated to a deity were not necessarily in specific fulfilment of a vow but could be a
more generalised expression of piety. Such gifts might include objects of low intrinsic value, 112 Catherine Johns
e,g. wood or terracotta (which, contra Millett, certainly can be and are described as hoards
where appropriate), intended to draw a deity’s attention to a request, and also gifts in cash and
kind made by the pious towards the running of the cult site. and as thank-offerings. In Classical
contexts, and surely also in Roman Britain, these could have included animals for sacrifice or
consumption, other types of food and probably materials and craftsmanship donated by
worshippers to the building and maintenance of a shrine or temple. The wealth of a temple
could also encompass much that had not been given but nevertheless formed part of its earnings
or production: for example, sacrificial animals could be kept and bred as a temple flock or herd.
Votive gifts of cash or bullion could be used to purchase other goods or services, but would not
thereby be rendered secular.
We can identify four categories of objects in the Roman period which may appear to have
been votive or religious.
a)
b)
c)
d)
single objects with the names or symbols of a god inscribed on them, or
hoards containing such
single objects or hoards bearing overt dedications to a
hoards of bullion or other material found in or near a known temple or church
hoards found in wet or waterlogged contexts which were clearly not buried for
safekeeping because they would have been irretrievable by the depositor.
(a) Objects inscribed with the names 01′ symbols of a god
Utensils and decorative items such as articles of jewellery frequently bore names and visual
devices relating to a deity. They were personal or family possessions, used or worn by an owner
who believed that these religious symbols were propitious and conducive to his or her good
fortune. Apotropaic symbolism was part of the belief-system of the ancient world, and remains
much more common today than most people would readily admit. The presence of personal or
domestic items bearing religious symbols in a Roman hoard does not of itself indicate that the
hoard was votive.
(b) Objects with votive inscriptions
Dedications to a deity or references to vows made or fulfilled are a different matter. Objects
such as the silver skillet from the Backworth treasure, dedicated to the Mother-goddesses by
Fabius Dubitatus, the silver plaques from Barkway dedicated to Mars with the classic formula
V.S.L.M., votum solvil libens merito, or their Christian counterpart from Water Newton, are all
overtly votive. (Walters 1921: no. 183, Painter 1977: no 12) They were given by
worshippers to a deity or shrine, and their ownership was thus transferred from the donor to the
god and his temple.
It does not follow from this that if buried, such items were never intended to be recovered.
Though dedicated to sacred purposes, votive objects were not necessarily withdrawn from
circulation in human society. They had become the property of a god or goddess, and could be
used in any appropriate way for the good of the temple, and temples were commercial
institutions as well as centres of worship. The Water Newton Christian hoard is a classic case
of an assemblage of plate intended for religious purposes, but the Coroner’s jury at the inquest Romano-British Preciolls-metal Hoards.· comments on lv/arlin MilleU’s paper 113
held in September 1975 quite rightly considered this no hindrance to declaring the hoard
Treasure Trove.
(c) Hoardsfrom sacred/temple sites
Hoards found at a known temple site do not necessarily belong to a single category, and those
which had a higll intrinsic value in antiquity, i.e. gold and silver hoards, were re-usable in a
sense which does not apply to hoards of terracotta lamps or wooden statuettes. If we take first
the objects classed under (b) above, those with specific dedications to a deity, we still have to
infer the reason for their burial. One argument, which M. would presumably support, is that the
administrators of the temple had chosen to put them beyond human reach because they
belonged to the god. This would prevent the cult site from benefiting from the wealth which
was represented by coinage and precious-metal objects.
Evidence from Egyptian papyri shows that although temples received certain official
subventions, their assets were also subject to taxation (Wallace 1938: 238–254). In times of
religious persecution, such as the persecution of Christians in the 3rd century AD and of
pagans at the end of the 4th century, the wealth of places of worship was under threat of seizure
and confiscation. There were occasions when temple wealth was raided for secular purposes;
for example, Cleopatra VII of Egypt used this resource to help finance her armies: ‘she slew
many of the foremost men .. . and she proceeded to gather vast wealth from their estates and
from various other sources both profane and sacred, sparing not even the most holy shrines … ‘
(Cassius Dio: 51, 5). Gold and silver were wealth, as were land and other possessions, and
organised temple and church sites were commercial entities subject to the same economic
conditions and pressures as the society of which they formed part, including taxation, the threat
of theft, civil disturbance, ordinary living expenses and the maintenance of land and buildings
(Bowman 1986: 107, 197). Temples and churches therefore required cash, and made use of it.
It is also relevant that one of the businesses conducted at some cult centres was banking,
including the granting of loans. There is ample evidence for private and corporate wealth being
stored under the guardianship of a deity and the deity’s human agents at major sacred sites such
as Delphi, Delos and Ephesos; Herodian, writing of the Temple of Peace in Rome, comments;
‘the temple was also the richest in Rome, since it was adorned with offerings of gold and silver
that had been placed there because they were safe. Everyone used it as a deposit for his
possessions’. (Herodian L 14, 2-3. See also Juvenal 14, 260-1). Christ expelling the
moneychangers from the Temple is also apposite (Matthew 21 : 12). The safekeeping of
valuables under the guardianship of a god was not merely a pious conceit but a practical
business proposition. Thus. bullion hoards found at a known cult centre might not even form
part of a temple’s own wealth, but could have belonged to private individuals, firms or official
organisations. In passing and in connection with the Thetford treasure, it may be noted that one
of the recorded functions of the relatively obscure god Faunus was to guard treasure (Johns &
Potter 1983: 49)
The possibility of votive status was raised in the discussion of the Thetford treasure (Johns
& Potter 1983: 73-74) and the early-Roman Hockwold treasure (Johns 1986: 10-11). The latter
had hitherto been widely regarded as a hoard of loot, though the objects are not quite typical
Hacksilber as seen in late-Roman assemblages such as that from Traprain Law (Curle 1923),
and the findspot is near a known temple complex. The deliberately damaged condition of the
Hockwold silver cups could conceivably indicate votive or ritual status rather than looting,
because it would have prevented their lise for their original secular, domestic purpose. It would 114 Catherine Johns
not, however, have prevented re-cycling as bullion if required. No firm conclusions were
reached in either case simply because the evidence is inconclusive, but both publications
demonstrate that this question is not one which has been ignored or avoided by those who study
the objects in Roman hoards.
In the Roman world there was always an acute need for gold and silver, and the pressures
against taking cash out of circulation were strong. To assume that because gold or silver was
buried in a sacred precinct it had been removed permanently from the contemporary economy
seems far more dubious than the assumption that in most cases it was simply in storage.
Deposits of such items as terracotta votive statuettes are often dumps of non-recyclable religious
gifts (e.g. Potter 1989). They are votive, because they were presented to a god, and they may
well have been interred with appropriate ceremony, but they were buried to make room for new
gifts. They would not have been recovered because they could perform no further service for the
temple. Gold and silver votives could continue to benefit the institution to which they had been
donated.
(d) Hoards from waterlogged contexts
There is no doubt that objects were, and still are, permanently given up for good luck by
depositing them in water, and I am certainly not claiming that the practice was unknown or
even uncommon in the Roman period. nor do I wish to challenge the theories of prehistorians
trying to understand and classify the many hoards of prehistoric bronze weapons and the like
deposited in water (Bradley 1990). We should not, however, leap to hasty conclusions about
objects deposited in apparently wet conditions; not all were deliberately and permanently
abandoned by human owners. We have to be sure of the circumstances. Built cisterns, fountains
and pools, as opposed to natural rivers and lakes, can usually be regularly trawled for the coins
thrown in by visitors, just as they are today. Moreover, there is post-medieval evidence from
Denmark for the safekeeping, not religious dedication, of silverware by depositing it in bags in
the shallows of lakes or bogs, a practice which might conceivably have existed elsewhere and at
other times CRandsborg 1980: 139). Until a Romano-British precious-metal treasure is found in
a waterlogged context which indisputably made it irrecoverable in antiquity, we can ponder the
matter.
Other Points from Millett’s Paper
1) Purchasing power of coin-hoards.
The comment that many Romano-British coin-hoards are of ‘modest purchasing power’ is an
unacceptably subjective one. Modest by whose standards? The wealth represented by a given
hoard of cash at any period will be perceived differently by different people. One person’ s lifesavings may equal another’s tax-bill for a year, whether in the 4th century AD or the 20th. The
changing pattern of coin issue, use and hoarding in the later Empire is a subject which
deserves, and is receiving, much thought, but the issues are a good deal more complicated than
M. implies. Arbitrary judgements are unlikely to be useful in deepening our understanding.
2) Spoons in hoards.
Spoons do indeed feature prominently in late-Roman silver hoards from Britain and elsewhere,
a fact which is familiar to all who study silver plate. While there may be an arcane and magical
reason behind their presence in so many silver plate hoards, it seems unnecessary to look for Romano-British Precious-metal comments on Iv/artin paper lIS
one when there is an obvious common-sense explanation. A spoon is the smallest and most
personal item from a set of silver tableware, and is therefore the one likely to exist in the largest
numbers. Families who could afford huge multiple sets of large silver dishes and bowls and
ewers would have possessed correspondingly extensive sets of spoons: families who could
afford very little silver plate would be more likely to own spoons than any other class of
tableware. The balance of different vessel-types in earlier Roman silver hoards is altered by the
presence of silver drinking-cups, also personal and fairly small, but many silver spoons are also
known from the Early and Middle Empire. There is no mystery unless we choose to create one.
3) Aesthetic qualities of hoarded items
M. states that ‘aesthetic merits appear important in the selection and perhaps the hoarding of
the objects buried in the Mildenhall treasure … ‘ , another subjective statement which is incapable
of proof. We can reasonably assert that some of the items in the Mildenhall treasure are of
exceptionally fine technical and artistic quality in comparison with other surviving examples of
4th century silverware: indeed, they are of outstanding quality by the standards of any period.
What we cannot say is whether their owner selected them for concealment because they were
especially splendid: we do not know who the owner was, what other items he/she owned, and
what the occasion was for their deposition. For all we know, the owner may have possessed
infinitely more magnificent vessels, perhaps including gold plate, and buried the moderately
handsome pieces while carrying away the finest (Painter I 977b).
4) Attitudes to treasure
Finally, ‘coyness’ about treasure, and public attitudes to it: those of us who have spent the
whole of our professional careers trying to convey through publications, exhibition labels,
lectures and letters to the public that present-day monetary value does not equate with
archaeological importance, and who have been subjected to ordeal by journalist and media
hysteria whenever ‘treasure’ is found, can only feel unutterably weary when we read M.’s
jejune comments.
It is not archaeologists, or at any rate not those in the alleged ‘professional coterie’ which
deals with bullion hoards, who have created or encouraged the shallow and frivolous popular
perception of treasure. This view has long existed and is becoming ever more deeply
entrenched. The public perception of treasure is entirely independent of the work of
archaeologists – indeed, many members of the public are faintly surprised that archaeologists
have anything to do with the matter – and is based on the excitement about discovery and
riches which is natural in children, augmented by the ruthlessly materialistic values which have
increasingly characterised the last fifteen years or so.
5) Future work
In the preface to his important book The Romanization a/Britain, M. expresses the hope that
he has avoided the perpetuation of factoids, those myths and unsupported assertions which,
throUgil repetition alone, become accepted as trutllS, and adds ‘ If I have unwittingly created
new ‘factoids’ , I trust reviewers will unmercifully point them out’. (Millett 1990: xvi) While I
do not wish to be unmerciful, I have therefore felt no compunction in drawing attention to the
numerous factoids-in-the-making which are set out in M’s. article.
Research on the nature of hoarding in Roman Britain, whether of precious metal or other
materials, and on the objects which were hoarded, including coins, will undoubtedly benefit 116 Catherine Johns
from increased debate If we can dispense with blatant factoids like the mythical British
Museum closed-shop invented by M., and avoid unnecessary and unproductive confrontation,
one of the outmoded masculine devices which still bedevil our discipline, we might be able to
build on the work of the last 20 years or more and make some major advances in the
interpretation of Roman precious-metal hoards and their contents. That is an aim upon which
we can all surely agree.
Acknowledgements
I should like to thank the following colleagues for their helpful comments: Don Bailey, Roger
Bland, Ian Kinnes, Ian Longworth, Stuart Needham, Tim Potter, Jenny Price, Ian Stead and
Gill VarndelL
Bibliography
Aitchison, N.B. 1988. Roman wealth, native ritual: coin hoards within and beyond Roman Britain, World
Archaeology 2012: 270-283.
Archer, S. 1979. Late Roman gold and silver coin hoards in Britain: a gazetteer, in P.l. Casey (ed.) The
End oj Roman Britain, 29-64. Oxford.
Baratte, F. & Painter, K.S. (eds) 1989. Tre.wl’s d’orfevrel’ie Paris.
Bowman, A. 1986. Egypt after the Pharaohs. London.
Bradley, R. 1990. The Passage oj Arms. Cambridge.
Cassius Dio. Roman History (Loeb edn, trans!. E. Cary, Cambridge, Mass. 1914 – 1970).
Curle, A. 1923. The Treasure oJTraprain. A Scottish Hoard oj Roman Silver Plate. Glasgow.
Gri.i.nhagen, W. 1954. Del’ SchatzJlInd von Gross Bodungen. Berlin.
Hawkins, E. 1850. Notices of a remarkable collection of ornaments of the Roman period, connected with
the worship of the Deae Matres, and recently pmchased for the British Museum,
Archaeological Journal 8: 36-44.
Hen ig, M . 1984. Religion in Roman Brita in. London.
Herodian. (Loeb edn., trans!. C.R. Whittaker. Cambridge, Mass., 1969).
Johns, C. 1981 The Risley Park Silver Lanx: a lost antiquity from Roman Britain, Antiquaries Journal
61: 53-72
Johns. C. 1982. Sex or Symbol, erotic images of Greece and Rome. London.
Johns. C. 1986. The Roman Silver Cups from Hockwold, NoIfolk. Archaeologia 108: 1- 13
Johns, C. 1990. Research on Roman Silver Plate, Journal 0/ Roman Archaeology 3: 28- 43.
Johns, C. 1995 (forthcoming). Jewellery in Roman Britain. London.
Johns, C. & Painter, K.S. 1991 TIle Risley Park Lanx ‘rediscovered’, Minerva 2/6, 6-13.
JolUls, C. & Potter. T. W. 1983. The Thetford Treasure; Roman Jewellery and Silver. London.
Juvena!. Satires (Loeb edn., trans!. G.G. Ramsay. Cambridge, Mass., 1918/1979)
King, C. 1981. Late Roman silver hoards in Britain and the problem of clipped siliquae, British
Numismatic Journal 51: 5-31.
KilnzL E. 1993. Die Alamannenbeule alls dem Rhein bei Neupot::.. Mainz.
Melville Jones. l.R. 1993. Testimonia NlImal’ia. Greek and Texis concerning Ancient Greek
Coinage. London.
Millett, M. 1990. The Romaniwtion of Britain. Cambridge. Romano-British Preciolls-metal Hoard.<i: comments on Martin Alii/ell’s paper 117
Oliver, A. 1977. Silver/or the Gods. Toledo.
Painter, K. 1977a. The Water Nelvton Early (‘hristian Silver. London.
Painter, K. 1977b. The Mildenhall Treasure. London.
Painter, K. 1994. Booty from a Roman villa, /vlinerva, 5/1, 22-27.
Potter, T. W. 1989. Una Stipe Votiva da Ponte di Nona. Rome.
Randsborg, K. 1980. The Viking Age in Denmark. London.
Reece. R. 1988. Interpreting Roman Hoards. World Archaeology 2012: 261-269.
Robertson. A. (forthcoming). InventOlY o(Coin Hoards/rom Roman Britain.
Strong, D. 1966. Greek and Roman Gold and Silver Plate. London.
Stukeley, W. J 736. An account 0/ a large Silver Plate 0/ antique basso relievo, Roman workmanship,
found in Derbyshire, 1729. London.
Vickers, M. J 994. Nabataea. India. Gaul and Carthage: reflections on Hellenistic and Roman gold vessels
and red-gloss pottery, American Journal of Archaeology 98: 231- 248.
Wallace. S. L. 1938. Taxation in Egypt/rom Augmtus to Dioc/etian. Princeton.
Walters, H.B. 1921. Catalogue of the Silver Plate, (Greek, Etruscan and Roman), in the Bnlish Museum.
London.
Add a comment